On the Mark: A Theory of Floating Exchange Rates Based on Real Interest Differentials
1979; American Economic Association; Volume: 69; Issue: 4 Linguagem: Inglês
ISSN
1944-7981
Autores Tópico(s)Global Financial Crisis and Policies
ResumoMuch of the recent work on floating exchange rates goes under the name of the or view; the exchange rate is viewed as moving to equilibrate the international demand for stocks of assets, rather than the international demand for flows of goods as under the more traditional view. But within the asset view there are two very different approaches. These approaches have conflicting implications in particular for the relationship between the exchange rate and the interest rate. The first approach might be called the theory because it assumes that prices are perfectly flexible.' As a consequence of the flexible-price assumption, changes in the nominal interest rate reflect changes in the expected inflation rate. When the domestic interest rate rises relative to the foreign interest rate, it is because the domestic currency is expected to lose value through inflation and depreciation. Demand for the domestic currency falls relative to the foreign currency, which causes it to depreciate instantly. This is a rise in the exchange rate, defined as the price of foreign currency. Thus we get a positive relationship between the exchange rate and the nominal interest differential. The second approach might be called the theory because it assumes that prices are sticky, at least in the short run.2 As a consequence of the sticky-price assumption, changes in the nominal interest rate reflect changes in the tightness of monetary policy. When the domestic interest rate rises relative to the foreign rate it is because there has been a contraction in the domestic money supply relative to domestic money demand without a matching fall in prices. The higher interest rate at home than abroad attracts a capital inflow, which causes the domestic currency to appreciate instantly. Thus we get a negative relationship between the exchange rate and the nominal interest differential. The Chicago theory is a realistic description when variation in the inflation differential is large, as in the German hyperinflation of the 1920's to which Frenkel first applied it. The Keynesian theory is a realistic description when variation in the inflation differential is small, as in the Canadian float against the United States in the 1950's to which Mundell first applied it. The problem is to develop a model that is a realistic description when variation in the inflation differential is moderate, as it has been among the major industrialized countries in the 1970's. This paper develops a model which is a version of the asset view of the exchange rate, in that it emphasizes the role of expectations and rapid adjustment in capital markets. The innovation is that it combines the Keynesian assumption of sticky prices with the Chicago assumption that there are secular rates of inflation. It then turns out that the exchange rate is negatively related to the nominal interest differential, but positively related to the expected long-run inflation differential. The exchange rate differs from, or overshoots, its equilibrium value by an amount *Assistant professor, University of California-Berkeley. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the December 1977 meetings of the Econometric Society in New York. I would like to thank Rudiger Dornbusch, Stanley Fischer, Jerry Hausman, Dale Henderson, Franco Modigliani, and George Borts for comments. 'See papers by Jacob Frenkel and by John Bilson. 2The most elegant asset-view statement of the Keynesian approach is by Rudiger Dornbusch (1976c), to which the present paper owes much. Roots lie in J. Marcus Fleming and Robert Mundell (1964, 1968). They argued that if capital were perfectly mobile, a nonzero interest differential would attract a potentially infinite capital inflow, with a large effect on the exchange rate. More recently, Victor Argy and Michael Porter, Jiirg Niehans, Dornbusch (1976a,b,c), Michael Mussa (1976) and Pentti Kouri (1 976a,b) have introduced the role of expectations into the Mundell-Fleming framework.
Referência(s)