Artigo Revisado por pares

Learning, political regimes and the liberalisation of trade

2010; Wiley; Volume: 50; Issue: 6 Linguagem: Inglês

10.1111/j.1475-6765.2010.01982.x

ISSN

1475-6765

Autores

Covadonga Meseguer, Abel Escribà‐Folch,

Tópico(s)

Social Policy and Reform Studies

Resumo

European Journal of Political ResearchVolume 50, Issue 6 p. 775-810 Learning, political regimes and the liberalisation of trade COVADONGA MESEGUER, COVADONGA MESEGUER Centre for Research and Teaching in Economics, Mexico City, Mexico and ICREA, Barcelona, Spain;Search for more papers by this authorABEL ESCRIBÀ-FOLCH, ABEL ESCRIBÀ-FOLCH Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, SpainSearch for more papers by this author COVADONGA MESEGUER, COVADONGA MESEGUER Centre for Research and Teaching in Economics, Mexico City, Mexico and ICREA, Barcelona, Spain;Search for more papers by this authorABEL ESCRIBÀ-FOLCH, ABEL ESCRIBÀ-FOLCH Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, SpainSearch for more papers by this author First published: 16 November 2010 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2010.01982.xCitations: 11Read the full textAboutPDF ToolsRequest permissionExport citationAdd to favoritesTrack citation ShareShare Give accessShare full text accessShare full-text accessPlease review our Terms and Conditions of Use and check box below to share full-text version of article.I have read and accept the Wiley Online Library Terms and Conditions of UseShareable LinkUse the link below to share a full-text version of this article with your friends and colleagues. Learn more.Copy URL Abstract In this article, the probability of opening to trade is related to a country's propensity to learn from other countries in its region. It is argued that countries have different motivations to learn, depending upon the responsiveness and accountability of their political regimes. Whereas democracies cannot afford to be dogmatic, authoritarian regimes are less motivated to learn from the experience of others, even if they embrace policies that fail. Using data on trade liberalisation for 57 developing countries in the period 1970–1999, it is found that democracies confronting economic crises are more likely to liberalise trade as a result of learning; among democracies, presidential systems seem to learn more, whereas personalist dictatorial regimes are the most resistant to learning from the experience of others. References Aspe, P. (1993). El Camino Mexicano de la Transformación Económica. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica. Baker, A. (2003). Why is trade reform so popular in Latin America? A consumption based theory of trade policy preferences. World Politics 55: 423– 455. Bates, R.H. (2008). When things fell apart: State failure in late-century Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press. Beck, T., Keefer, P. & Clarke, G. (2000). Database on political institutions. Washington, DC: World Bank. Bennett, C. & Howlett, M. (1992). The lessons of learning: Reconciling theories of policy learning and policy change. Policy Sciences 25: 275– 294. Brambor, T., Clark, W.R. & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis 14: 63– 82. Bresser, L.C., Maravall, J.M. & Przeworski, A. (1993). Las Reformas Económicas en las Nuevas Democracias. Madrid: Alianza Editorial. Brooker, P. (2000). Non-democratic regimes: Theory, government and politics. London: Macmillan. Brooks, S.M & Kurtz, M.J. (2008). Capital, trade and the political economies of reform. American Journal of Political Science 51(4): 703– 720. Bueno de Mesquita, B. et al. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Carter, D. & Signorino, C.S. (2007). Back to the Future: Modeling Time Dependence in Binary Data. Unpublished manuscript. Cheibub, J.A. & Gandhi, J. (2004). Classifying Political Regimes: A Six-fold Classification of Democracies and Dictatorships. Paper presented at the annual APSA meeting, Chicago, IL, September. Corbo, V. (2000). Economic policy reform in Latin America. In A. Krueger (ed.), Economic policy reform. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. De la Madrid, M. (2004). Cambio de Rumbo. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica. Drazen, A. (2000). Political economy in macroeconomics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Drazen, A. & Easterly, W. (2001). Do crises induce reform? Simple empirical tests of conventional wisdom. Economics and Politics 13(2): 129– 158. Edwards, S. (1995). Crisis and reform in Latin America: From despair to hope. Washington, DC/Oxford: World Bank/Oxford University Press. Escribà-Folch, A. (2009). Do authoritarian institutions mobilize economic cooperation? Constitutional Political Economy 20(1): 71– 93. Etheredge, L. (1981). Government learning: An overview. In S.L. Long (ed.), The handbook of political behavior, 2nd edn. New York: Pergamon Press. Fernández, R. & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review 81(5): 1146– 1155. Freeman, R. (2006). Learning in public policy. In M. Moran, M. Rein & R. Goodin (eds), The Oxford handbook of public policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Geddes, B. (1995). Challenging the conventional wisdom. In L. Diamond & M. Plattner (eds), Economic reform and democracy. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Geddes, B. (1999). What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science 2: 115– 144. Gelman, A. et al. (2004). Bayesian data analysis, 2nd edn. London: Chapman & Hall. Gilardi, F. (2010). Who learns from what in policy diffusion processes? American Journal of Political Science 54(3): 650– 666. Gill, J. (2002). Bayesian methods: A social and behavioral sciences approach. Boca Raton, FL: Chapman & Hall/CRC. Gowda, R. & Fox, J. (2002). Judgments, decisions and public policy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Grossman, S.J. & Stiglitz, J. (1976). Information and competitive price systems. American Economy Review Papers and Proceedings 66: 246– 253. Guisinger, A. (2005). Understanding Cross Country Patterns in Trade Liberalization. Doctoral dissertation, Yale University. Haggard, S. & Kaufman, R. (eds) (1992). The politics of economic adjustment: International constraints, distributive conflicts and the state. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Haggard, S. & Kaufman, R. (1995). The political economy of democratic transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Hall, P. (1993). Policy paradigms, social learning and the state: The case of economic policy making in Britain. Comparative Politics 25(3): 275– 296. Harberger, A. (1993). Secrets of success: A handful of heroes. American Economic Review 83(2): 343– 350. Heclo, H. (1974). Modern social politics in Britain and in Sweden. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Hellwig, T. & Samuels, D. (2007). Electoral accountability and the variety of democratic regimes. British Journal of Political Science 38(1): 65– 90. Hiscox, M. (2001). Class versus industry cleavages: Inter-industry factor mobility and the politics of trade. International Organization 55(1): 1– 46. Horn, K. & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Trade liberalization and growth: New evidence. Working paper 10152. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Iglesias, E. (1992). Reflections on economic development: Toward a new Latin American consensus. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank. Kahler, M. (1990). Orthodoxy and its alternatives: Explaining approaches to stabilization and adjustment. In J. Nelson (ed.), Economic crisis and policy choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Kahler, M. (1992). External influence, conditionality and the politics of adjustment. In S. Haggard & R. Kaufman (eds), The politics of economic adjustment. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Knill, C. (2005). Cross-national policy convergence: Concepts, approaches and explanatory factors. Journal of European Public Policy 12(5): 764– 774. Krueger, A. (1993). Political economy of policy reform in developing countries. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Lee, C.K. & Strang, D. (2006). The international diffusion of public-sector downsizing: Network emulation and theory-driven learning. International Organization 60(4): 883– 909. Levi-Faur, D. & Jordana, J. (2005). The rise of regulatory capitalism: The global diffusion of a new order. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Sciences 598(1): 102– 124. Levy, J.S. (1994). Learning and foreign policy: Sweeping a conceptual minefield. International Organization 48(2): 279– 312. Linz, J.J. (1990). The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy 1(1): 51– 69. Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V. & Rosendorff, P. (2000). Free trade: Democracies, autocracies and international trade. American Political Science Review 94(2): 305– 321. May, P. (1992). Policy learning and failure. Journal of Public Policy 12(4): 331– 354. Meseguer, C. (2009). Learning, policy making and market reforms. New York: Cambridge University Press. Meseguer, C. & Gilardi, F. (2009). What is new in the study of policy diffusion? Review of International Political Economy 16(3): 527– 543. Milner, H. & Kubota, K. (2005). Why the move to free trade? Democracy and trade policy in the developing countries. International Organization 59: 157– 193. Ndulu, B. et al. (eds) (2007). The political economy of economic growth in Africa, 1960–2000, 2 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Persson, T., Roland, G. & Tabellini, G. (1997). Separation of powers and political accountability. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1163– 1202. Persson, T., Roland, G. & Tabellini, G. (2000). Comparative politics and public finance. Journal of Political Economy 108(6): 1121– 1161. Pitlik, H. (2008). The impact of growth performance and political regime type on economic policy liberalization. Kyklos 61(2): 258– 278. Powell, G.B. & Whitten, G.D. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science 37(2): 391– 414. Przeworski, A. et al. (2000). Democracy and development: Political institutions and material well-being in the world, 1950–1990. New York: Cambridge University Press. Rodrik, D. (1994). The rush to free trade in the developing world: Why so late? Why now? Will it last? In S. Haggard & S. Webb (eds), Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization and economic adjustment. Washington, DC/Oxford: World Bank/Oxford University Press. Rodrik, D. (1996). Understanding economic policy reform. Journal of Economic Literature 34: 9– 41. Rose, R. (1991). What is lesson-drawing? Journal of Public Policy 2(1): 3– 30. Rudra, N. (2008). Globalization and the race to the bottom in developing countries: Who really gets hurt? New York: Cambridge University Press. Sabatier, P.A. & Jenkins-Smith, H.C. (1993). Policy change and learning: An advocacy coalition approach. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Sachs, J. & Warner, A. (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1– 118. Samuels, D. (2004). Presidentialism and accountability for the economy in comparative perspective. American Political Science Review 98(3): 425– 436. Shipan, C. & Volden, C. (2008). The mechanisms of policy diffusion. American Journal of Political Science 52(4): 840– 857. Simmons, B. & Elkins, Z. (2004). The globalization of liberalization: Policy diffusion in the international political economy. American Political Science Review 98(1): 171– 189. Simmons, B. et al. (2008). The global diffusion of markets and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Stiglitz, J. (1998 ). Knowledge for Development: Economic Science, Economic Policy and Economic Advice. Paper presented at the annual World Bank conference on Development Economics, Washington, DC, 20–21 April. Stokes, S. (ed.) (2001). Public support for market reforms in new democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press. Stone, D. (1999). Learning lessons and transferring policy across time, space and disciplines. Politics 19(1): 51– 59. Tommasi, M. & Velasco, A. (1995). Where are we in the political economy of reform? New York: C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics. Toye, J. (1994). Comments to in search of a manual for technopols. In J. Williamson (ed), The political economy of policy reform. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Ulfelder, J. (2005). Contentious collective action and the breakdown of authoritarian regimes. International Political Science Review 26(3): 311– 334. Van de Walle, N. (2001). African economies and the politics of permanent crisis, 1979–1999. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Volden, C. (2006). States as policy laboratories: Emulating success in the children's health insurance program. American Journal of Political Science 50(2): 294– 312. Volden, C., Ting, M.M. & Carpenter, D.P. (2008). A formal model of learning and policy diffusion. American Political Science Review 102(3): 319– 332. Vreeland, J.R. (2003). The IMF and economic growth. New York: Cambridge University Press. Webb, R. (1994). Peru. In J. Williamson (ed.), The political economy of policy reform. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. West, M. & Harrison, J.P. (1997). Dynamic Bayesian forecasting and dynamic models. New York: Springer-Verlag. Weyland, K. (2002). The politics of market reforms in fragile democracies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Weyland, K. (2007). Bounded rationality and policy diffusion: Social sector reform in Latin America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Williamson, J. (ed.) (1994). The political economy of policy reform. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. World Bank. (2005). Economic growth in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform. Washington, DC: World Bank. Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? How legislatures impact economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science 52(2): 322– 343. Citing Literature Volume50, Issue6October 2011Pages 775-810 ReferencesRelatedInformation

Referência(s)