Implications for models in monetary policy
2010; Taylor & Francis; Volume: 17; Issue: 4 Linguagem: Inglês
10.1080/1350178x.2010.525040
ISSN1469-9427
Autores Tópico(s)Economic Theory and Policy
ResumoAbstract Monetary authorities have been implicated in the financial crisis of 2007–2008. John Muellbauer, for example, has blamed what he thought was initially inadequate policy responses by central banks to the crisis on their models, which are, in his words, 'overdue for the scrap heap'. This paper investigates the role of monetary policy models in the crisis and finds that (i) it is likely that monetary policy contributed to the financial crisis; and (ii) that an inappropriately narrow suite of models made this mistake easier. The core models currently used at prominent central banks were not designed to discover emergent financial fragility. In that respect John Muellbauer is right. But the implications drawn here are less dramatic than his: while the representative agent approach to micro-foundations now seems indefensible, other aspects of modern macroeconomics are not similarly suspect. The case made here is rather for expanding the suite of models used in the regular deliberations of monetary authorities, with new models that give explicit roles to the financial sector, to money and to the process of exchange. Recommending a suite of models for policy making entails no methodological innovation. That is what central banks do; though, of course, how they do it is open to improvement. The methodological innovation is the inclusion of a model that would be sensitive to financial fragility, a sensitivity that was absent in the run-up to the current financial crisis. Keywords: monetary policyfinancial crisismethodology of policy modelsJEL Codes:: B400E130E440E520 Notes 1. There are a number of excellent accounts of the crisis, such as Blanchard (2009 Blanchard, O.J. (2009), 'The Crisis: Basic Mechanisms, and Appropriate Policies', IMF Working Paper WP/09/80, Washington, DC [Google Scholar]) and Almunia et al. (2009) and recently Roberts (2010 Roberts, R. (2010), 'Gambling With Other People's Money: How Perverted Incentives Caused the Financial Crisis', Research Paper, Mercatus Centre at George Mason University, Arlington, VA [Google Scholar]) with a focus on the changes in financial sector incentives. The text focuses on those aspects most closely related to monetary policy and, consequently, misses a lot of the detail (especially of an institutional kind) in these broader accounts. 2. This was one of the less widely shared notions in the modern consensus on monetary policy. Or to be more precise it was one of the elements of the consensus which many monetary economists and central bankers felt was more open to further research and experience (Goodfriend 2005 Goodfriend, M. (2005), 'The Monetary Policy Debate Since October 1979: Lessons for Theory and Practice', Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Economic Review, 87 (2, part 2) 243–261 [Google Scholar]; Mishkin 2007 Mishkin, F.S. 2007. Monetary Policy Strategy, The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. [Crossref] , [Google Scholar]). 3. Note that Bernanke and Gertler (1999 Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. 1999. Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility. Economic Review, Q(V), 17–51 [Google Scholar]) did not recommend policy paralysis; on the contrary they reasoned that 'asset price crashes have done sustained damage to the economy only in cases when monetary policy remained unresponsive or actively reinforced deflationary pressures' (Bernanke and Gertler 1999 Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. 1999. Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility. Economic Review, Q(V), 17–51 [Google Scholar], p. 18). And it seemed that the required response was precisely the response indicated by a flexible inflation targeting system. 4. While 'monetary policy' typically means the interest rate policy of a modern central bank, there are other instruments available to central banks, including reserve requirements, quantitative adjustments to the monetary base and usually a role in the regulation of financial sector firms (Borio and Disyatat 2009 Borio, C., and Disyatat, P. (2009), 'Unconventional Monetary Policies: An Appraisal', BIC Working Paper No. 292, Basel [Google Scholar]). 5. Blinder (2005 Blinder, A.S. (2005), 'Understanding the Greenspan Standard', Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansan City Symposium on The Greenspan Era: Lessons for the Future, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 25–27 August [Google Scholar]) argued that the 'mop up' approach passed a 'severe' stress test with the unwinding of the dot.com bubble from 2000 to 2002. 6. For Mishkin (2008 MishkinF.S. (2008), 'How Should We Respond to Asset Price Bubbles?', Speech at the Wharton Financial Institutions Center and Oliver Wyman Institute's Annual Financial Risk Roundtable, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, 15 May [Google Scholar]) a prerequisite for taking policy action against even a credit bubble is that the bubble reflects market failure of some kind. 7. William Poole – then chief executive of the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis – observed the same in 2007 (Poole 2007 Poole, W. (2007), 'Understanding the Fed', Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Economic Review, 89(1), 3–13 [Google Scholar]). 8. The awareness of the data constraints under which policy is made in real time is hardly new, and the point has been made repeatedly in the post-War period, by, to name just a few: Friedman (1947 Friedman, M. 1947. Lerner on the Economics of Control. Journal of Political Economy, 55(5): 405–416. [Google Scholar]), Meltzer (1987 Meltzer, A.H. 1987. Limits of Short-Run Stabilization Policy. Economic Inquiry, 25: 1–14. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] , [Google Scholar]) and McCallum (1994 McCallum, B.T. 1994. Specification of Policy Rules and Performance Measures in Multicountry Stimulation Studies. Journal of International Money and Finance, 13(3): 259–275. [Google Scholar]) and more recently by Orphanides in a series of papers, including Orphanides (2002 Orphanides, A. 2002. Monetary Policy Evaluation with Noisy Information. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50: 605–631. [Google Scholar]). Two important lessons have emerged from this literature (Orphanides 2002 Orphanides, A. 2002. Monetary Policy Evaluation with Noisy Information. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50: 605–631. [Google Scholar], p. 606): first, the evaluation of past policy must be sensitive to the data available in real time to the policy makers. For the case at hand this means looking at the Fed's best estimates of output and inflation in the critical years between 2001 and 2005, not an evaluation of what seems optimal with the benefit of the revised data. Second, realistic policy alternatives have to be based on data that is both available and measurable with a high signal-to-noise ratio. From this perspective it is not useful to examine the merit of alternative policy paths in 2001 to 2005 based on the assumption that policy makers could have known that an asset bubble was emerging in the US housing market. The quantitative importance of noise in the data on the merit of alternative policy paths was demonstrated through simulation by Orphanides (2002 Orphanides, A. 2002. Monetary Policy Evaluation with Noisy Information. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50: 605–631. [Google Scholar]). He contrasts the substantial gains that appear within the grasp of an activist monetary authority when they operate with noiseless data, with the substantially inferior results generated by the same activism when the relevant data is noisy. Indeed with noise a much less activist policy rule delivers substantially better stabilisation for the economy. The same result, favouring a 'conservative' central banker, emerges when the monetary authorities grapple not only with noisy data but with uncertainty about the transmission mechanism and expectations (Orphanides and Williams 2008 Orphanides, A. and Williams, J.C. 2008. Learning, Expectations Formation, and Pitfalls of Optimal Control Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55: S80–S86. [Google Scholar]). 9. These 'nowcasts' are released with a five-year time lag, allowing consideration of the critical 2002 to 2005 period at the time of writing. 10. John Muellbauer (2007 Muellbauer, J. (2007), 'Housing, Credit and Consumer Expenditure', Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City's 2007 Jackson Hole Symposium on Housing, Housing Finance, Monetary Policy, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 30 August–1 September [Google Scholar]) argued that the Fed's concern with the risk of deflation was a misplaced fear that the Japanese episode of the 1990s could be repeated in the USA. 11. There were many other factors such as regulatory mistakes or even 'holes' in financial regulation as well as psychological factors such as overoptimism that played a role in the increased leverage and perverse incentives that encouraged risk taking in the banking sector (Blanchard 2009 Blanchard, O.J. (2009), 'The Crisis: Basic Mechanisms, and Appropriate Policies', IMF Working Paper WP/09/80, Washington, DC [Google Scholar]; Roberts 2010 Roberts, R. (2010), 'Gambling With Other People's Money: How Perverted Incentives Caused the Financial Crisis', Research Paper, Mercatus Centre at George Mason University, Arlington, VA [Google Scholar]). 12. Models used by central banks in the policy process will usually disaggregate this IS relationship in a number of constituent relationships by different types of real expenditure (Goodhart 2005 Goodhart, C.A.E. (2005), 'The Future of Central Banking', LSE Financial Markets Group Special Paper No. 62, London [Google Scholar], pp. 3–4). 13. As Sims (2002 Sims, C.A. 2002. The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy Process. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 1–40. [Crossref] , [Google Scholar]) showed, the policy process at leading central banks uses model results combined with non-model information about the economy, from surveys and other data, as well as subjective judgments. 14. While they specify a continuum of households their aggregation is trivial due to the assumptions of separable utility and complete contingent markets (Fernández-Villaverde et al. 2010 Fernández-Villaverde, J., Guerrón-Quintana, P.A., and Rubio-Ramírez, J.F. (2010), 'Reading the Recent Monetary History of the US, 1959–2007', NBER Working Paper 15929, Cambridge, MA [Google Scholar], p. 6). 15. That is to say without 'sound justification' (Fernández-Villaverde et al. 2010 Fernández-Villaverde, J., Guerrón-Quintana, P.A., and Rubio-Ramírez, J.F. (2010), 'Reading the Recent Monetary History of the US, 1959–2007', NBER Working Paper 15929, Cambridge, MA [Google Scholar], p. 5). 16. Identifying the key institutions (those where stress and failure will have consequences beyond the 'limited group of customers and counterparties' (Crockett 1997 Crockett, A. (1997), 'Why Is Financial Stability a Goal of Public Policy?', Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City's 1997 Jackson Hole Symposium on Maintaining Financial Stability in a Global Economy, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 28–30 August [Google Scholar], p. 10) is difficult in practice. The recent crisis suggests that well-informed central banks can err in this judgement. Nevertheless, reforms under consideration for financial regulation internationally emphasise the position of 'systemically important institutions'. 17. Important papers in this literature include: Tsomocos (2003a Tsomocos, D.P. 2003a. Equilibrium Analysis, Banking and Financial Instability. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 39: 619–655. [Google Scholar]; 2003b TsomocosD.P. (2003b), 'Equilibrium Analysis, Banking, Contagion and Financial Fragility', Bank of England Working Paper No. 175, London [Google Scholar]) and Goodhart et al. (2004 Goodhart, C.A.E., Sunirand, P. and Tsomocos, D. 2004. A Model to Analyse Financial Fragility: Applications. Journal of Financial Stability, 1: 1–30. [Google Scholar], 2006 Goodhart, C.A.E., Sunirand, P. and Tsomocos, D. 2006. A Model to Analyse Financial Fragility. Economic Theory, 27: 107–142. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] , [Google Scholar]). 18. This discussion draws on Bårdsen et al. (2006, pp. 9–13), but the criteria envisioned for an adequate model here differ notably from his list. 19. Heterogeneity in the banking sector is critical for a model of financial fragility: in a representative agent model either all banks (the bank) will fail, or not, while the feature of financial fragility that is of interest here is the failure of some banks, while others survive, perhaps in a more fragile condition. Further there is no possibility of an inter-bank market (the source of much contagious interaction between banks and prominent in this regard in the present crisis) without heterogeneous banks (Goodhart et al. 2006 Goodhart, C.A.E., Sunirand, P. and Tsomocos, D. 2006. A Model to Analyse Financial Fragility. Economic Theory, 27: 107–142. [Crossref], [Web of Science ®] , [Google Scholar]). Some DSGE models have incorporated financial friction by way of a financial accelerator, in which a representative agent model with asymmetric information generates balance sheet effects for the firm through one-period stochastic optimal debt-contracts with costly verification. Though this is a successful strategy to include balance sheet effects, it does not create any role for banks in the model, nor is there any room for regulatory policies in a framework where the equilibrium is always constrained efficient (Goodhart et al. 2010 Goodhart, C.A.E., Osorio, C. and Tsomocos, D. 2010. "The Optimal Monetary Policy Instrument, Inflation Versus Asset Price Targeting, and Financial Stability". In Inflation Targeting Twenty Years On, Edited by: Cobham, D., Eitrheim, Ø., Gerlach, S. and Qvigstad, J.F. 192–231. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar], p. 2). 20. Goodhart et al. (e.g. 2006 Goodhart, C.A.E., Sunirand, P. and Tsomocos, D. 2004. A Model to Analyse Financial Fragility: Applications. Journal of Financial Stability, 1: 1–30. [Google Scholar] and 2004 Hoover, K.D. 2009. "Microfoundations and the Ontology of Macroeconomics". In The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy and Economics, Edited by: Kincaid, H. and Ross, D. 386–409. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]) build on earlier work in this direction by Dubey, Geanakoplos, and Shubik (2000 Dubey, P., Geanakopolis, J., and Shubik, M. (2000), 'Default in a General Equilibrium Model With Incomplete Markets', Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1247, New Haven [Google Scholar]) and Shubik and Wilson (1977 Shubik, M. and Wilson, C. 1977. The Optimal Bankruptcy Rule in a Trading Economy Using Fiat Money. Journal of Economics, 37: 337–354. [Google Scholar]). 21. The RAMSI model under development at the Bank of England (discussed below) is an example of the microeconomic foundations envisioned here. 22. Hoover (2010 HooverK.D. (2010), 'Microfoundations Programs', Paper prepared for the First International Symposium on the History of Economic Thought, The Integration of Micro and Macroeconomics From a Historical Perspective, University of Sāo Paulo, Brazil, 3–5 August [Google Scholar]) identified three distinct programmes to develop micro-foundations for macroeconomic models, which he called (i) the aggregation programme; (ii) the general-equilibrium programme; and (iii) the representative-agent programme. The micro-foundations described above are closer to the heterogeneity that Hoover identified in Keynes and the aggregation programme of Klein. By contrast, the micro-foundations used almost universally in modern macroeconomics are of the representative agent kind, on the shortcomings of which see Hoover (2008 Hoover, K.D. (2008), 'Idealizing Reduction: The Microfoundations of Macroeconomics', Mimeograph, Duke University, Durham, NC [Google Scholar], 2009 Hoover, K.D. 2009. "Microfoundations and the Ontology of Macroeconomics". In The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy and Economics, Edited by: Kincaid, H. and Ross, D. 386–409. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar] and 2010 HooverK.D. (2010), 'Microfoundations Programs', Paper prepared for the First International Symposium on the History of Economic Thought, The Integration of Micro and Macroeconomics From a Historical Perspective, University of Sāo Paulo, Brazil, 3–5 August [Google Scholar]). The tremendous problems of aggregation and the problems of working with the utility function of a representative agent as if the connection to the utility functions of individuals is not deeply problematic (and perhaps insurmountable) have never been answered (Hoover 2010 HooverK.D. (2010), 'Microfoundations Programs', Paper prepared for the First International Symposium on the History of Economic Thought, The Integration of Micro and Macroeconomics From a Historical Perspective, University of Sāo Paulo, Brazil, 3–5 August [Google Scholar]). Under these circumstances the widespread adoption of representative agent models has the character of an ideological response (Hoover 2009 Hoover, K.D. 2009. "Microfoundations and the Ontology of Macroeconomics". In The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy and Economics, Edited by: Kincaid, H. and Ross, D. 386–409. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]). 23. There are many reasons for this, including the belief by policy committee members that the additional information gives them a more accurate picture of the current state of the economy and hence a superior basis for their short-term forecasts of key variables; in Sims's words, 'several of those involved in subjective forecasting, at more than one central bank, expressed the view that the advantage of subjective forecasts is almost entirely in getting the current and the next quarter right' (Sims 2006 Sims, C.A. 2006. "Comments on Blinder's "The Case Against the Case Against Discretionary Fiscal Policy". In The Macroeconomics of Fiscal Policy, Edited by: Kopcke, R.W., Tootell, G.M.B. and Triest, R.K. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [Google Scholar], p. 21). The desire to respond to large and unusual events is another reason for the persistent use of the non-model information. A third reason is the belief that no single model captures the range of issues relevant to a MPC (Vickers 1999 Vickers, J. (1999), 'Economic Models and Monetary Policy', Speech to the Governors of the National Institute of Economic and Social Research, London, 18 May [Google Scholar]).
Referência(s)