Artigo Acesso aberto Revisado por pares

Why the Euro will Not Rival the Dollar

2008; Wiley; Volume: 11; Issue: 1 Linguagem: Inglês

10.1111/j.1468-2362.2008.00217.x

ISSN

1468-2362

Autores

Adam S. Posen,

Tópico(s)

Fiscal Policies and Political Economy

Resumo

Financial panics are indeed dramatic and, for many private individuals and economic policymakers, traumatic. They are rarely of lasting significance to the fate of nations or their currencies, however, as the prompt recovery of Brazil, Korea, Mexico and Russia from their travails a decade ago demonstrates – unless some fundamental political upheaval takes place as well (as happened in the case of Indonesia).1 1In fact, the most recent empirical literature suggests that the fastest growing countries are not just those most subject to financial crises, but that those economies still come out ahead of their more stable counterparts, net of the cost of crises. See Tornell and Westermann (2005). Even the United States unilaterally shutting the gold window in 1971 did not lead to a sustained shift out of dollars or free fall in the currency. Though difficult to maintain, this long-term perspective is useful while the United States at present experiences a panic in its many interlocking asset-backed securities markets, following years of large current account deficits and a concurrent sell-off of the dollar against the euro. But it would be a mistake to read too much into recent developments. In fact, they obscure the reality that the euro is at a temporary peak of influence, and the dollar will continue to benefit from the geopolitical sources of its global role which the euro cannot yet or soon, if ever, match. If the dollar is displaced from its global role either now or in the coming couple of decades, it will likely and unfortunately be in favour of global monetary fragmentation induced by failures of US political leadership, rather than by ascension of the euro to a leading role based on purely economic developments. This significant dependence of the dollar's future role on political as well as economic factors, however, suggests that the dollar's global role is vulnerable to foreign policy failures – that in fact some of the decline in the dollar's global role of late is already due to the foreign policy failures of the Bush administration, not just to current account imbalances and financial turmoil. Therefore, were the dollar to be displaced from a dominant role there is a real risk of fragmentation of the global monetary system reinforcing political fragmentation. Were there just to be bipolarity with the euro, that would be a much happier prospect and at least a smoother transition with fewer implications. Alas, that is not to be. With news reports at the moment that everyone from fashion models and rap stars to New York City souvenir store owners are seeking payment in euros instead of dollars, and with McDonald's running a television advertisement for its Dollar Menu on US broadcasters beginning with a bunch of typical American office workers muttering 'Dollar's looking weak …', it seems only logical to think recent turmoil may be the big event that pushes the dollar off its pedestal as the dominant international currency. Given the apparent readiness of the euro to provide an alternative for all these concerned individuals to accept in lieu of dollars, or even into which to switch their investments, the euro's ascent to at least comparable status with the dollar has a surface and popular plausibility. Indeed, some observers predicted before the euro's launch that the euro would some day rival the dollar as a reserve currency, if not also as a private store of value and means of account, producing a bipolar monetary system.2 2See Alogoskoufis and Portes (1992), Bergsten (1997a, b) and Portes and Rey (1998). Note that most of these economic analyses focus specifically on the reserve currency role, given availability (for the most part) of data on official currency holdings and the assumption that many other aspects of the dollar or euro's usage would follow shifts in this usage. That is not to say that they dismiss other aspects such as pegging by third countries or private-sector invoicing, but do not focus on them. In this view, the fundamental drivers of reserve currency shares were the relative economic size, financial depth and commitment to low inflation of the dollar and euro economic blocs, all of which could be expected to converge over time, if not favour the euro.3 3Given the extraordinary historic convergence of monetary policies and resulting inflation rates globally, not just between the United States and the eurozone, I will largely set aside this as a potential source of shift between euro and dollar. Later, Chinn and Frankel (2007) offered a since widely cited econometric projection of the shift in relative shares of the dollar and euro in central bank holdings, which bravely forecast dates for the crossing point (initially 2022, now updated to 2015), plus-or-minus depending upon the expansion of the eurozone's membership.4 4Frankel has demonstrated consistent regard for the importance of the economic size and financial depth criteria as determinative, having previously argued against risks to the dollar's relative standing prior to the existence of a truly sizeable and liquid currency zone to compete. See Frankel (1995). The entry or not of the United Kingdom into the eurozone, with its accompanying financial depth and liquidity via London's capabilities as well as its GDP size, would either accelerate or postpone the point of equalization – but it would be only a matter of time either way on this view. Offsetting this projected trend of increasing euro usage is the obvious inertia in dollar usage shown in the data, which is usually ascribed to incumbency advantages due to the network benefits from the already wide use of the dollar. Thus, these network effects could be expected to persist without being fully offsetting, barring incident, and in fact to diminish over time as the relative sizes of the dollar and euro currency networks converged. As Truman (2007) points out, however, these lagged effects explain 80–90% of the variation in reserve shares in the Chinn and Frankel (2007) estimations, and are thus what we really want to explain. It is also noteworthy that network effects have not as yet been measured directly since, at an aggregate level, they are an increasing function of the extent of euro or dollar usage which such studies attempt to explain, and thus can only show up as lagged values of the extent of that usage. Dooley et al. (1989) and Eichengreen and Mathieson (2000), with access to confidential IMF data on specific country reserve portfolios, found that the geographic composition of trade, the denomination of foreign debt and most importantly the choice of currency peg (if any) could explain the persistence of reserve shares – perhaps unsurprisingly, all being persistent variables themselves. The revealed importance of the lags could also reflect either other sources of inertia or omitted variables which play as large or a larger role in the choice of pegs and the other liquidity variables emphasized to date, as I will argue below. Some analysts have argued that the euro's attaining co-dominance simply awaited a significant series of policy mistakes or balance of payments crises on the part of the United States for the regime switch to occur, by overcoming this inertia (notably Bergsten 2005). Such a process is assumed, in those analysts' interpretation, to have been operative when sterling lost its role to the dollar in the 1930s, once the United Kingdom's balance of payments and monetary discipline flagged, and the dollar being spared such a fate in turn during the 1970s, only because neither the Deutschmark nor the yen was a viable alternative at the time. The existence of the alternative reserve currency was supposedly the key factor, conditional on the basic economic size and financial liquidity factors being in place, and thus recent events are ripe for an accelerated switch to the euro, if not a formal regime change. It is overdue and correct for American and other observers to shed any remnants of the excessive doubts about the euro's viability that prevailed in too many quarters from the mid-1990s onward, and to recognize that the euro has been an ample success within the limits of the monetary realm (Posen 2005). Recent developments in foreign exchange markets, with the euro reaching new historical highs against the dollar, may finally make that recognition near-universal. Yet, to go further and to argue that this is the turning point for the euro to equal the dollar in, or to displace the dollar from, its global role, however, would be misguided. There will be no abrupt displacement of the dollar from a dominant role in official reserve portfolios because official reserves are accumulated either to insure against speculative attacks or to pursue mercantilist goals. Both of those motivations result in portfolio rebalancing, meaning a tendency to increase official dollar holdings when the exchange rate declines. Longer-term choices of international currency commitments – such as which currency to peg to or to manage one's currency against – are not solely driven by financial factors either, but also by foreign policy motivations and security ties. It is not an accident, for example, that the CFA franc zone, where France still intervenes militarily, is the only group of countries outside of eurozone membership candidacy to peg to the euro, while those EU members with the strongest desire for independent security policies (Poland, Sweden and the United Kingdom) are the ones which have refused to enter the ERM II in preparation for eurozone membership. The source of all of these mistakes is too narrow and deterministic a focus on simple observable economic determinants of reserve currency holdings, and of global currency usage more broadly.5 5While a large literature in political science has emerged in the last 20 years on the political economy of monetary policy, the focus has tended to be on either monetary statecraft, the tactical use of exchange rate policy in specific instances (e.g. Henning 1994; Kirshner 1993). Those few that deal with currency choice (e.g. Cohen 1998) end up emphasizing the same trio of economic determinants of reserve status as typical in economics. A partial exception are the essays collected in Andrews (2006) and Kirshner (2003) and the contributions therein. More provocative are the broader historical syntheses of Maier (2006) and Strange (1996) on sources of American power which take currency usage as part of the package. The mainstream economics literature on currency status admits as much by its repeated frustration in accounting for the empirical behaviour of dollar holders either in the public sector, which is seen in the persistence of dollars in international reserves even though they do not hold value over the long term, as well as the persistence of dollar pegs seemingly at odds with optimal currency criteria. It is just as troubling regarding the private sector, given the apparent willingness of foreign investors to give the United States an 'exorbitant privilege' via accepting low-yielding US Treasuries and other dollar-denominated investments. This is why Hausmann and Sturzenegger (2006) were fully justified in resorting to the physics analogy of unobservable 'dark matter' to explain the gap in relative returns for dollar holders, which ultimately is the source of the United States' ability to run large current account deficits and (by identity) of foreigners' accumulation of dollar assets – although closer examination indicated that their specific contention about intangibles leading to high profits from US FDI abroad argument did not hold up.6 6See Gros (2006), Higgins et al. (2005) and Setser (2005) for extensive critiques of their view. The missing mass problem for pure economic explanations of currency behaviour is why Chinn and Frankel (2007) have to include such a large role for imputed 'network' effects via lags, even though there is little work done by that labelling. The missing mass in economic explanations is also why the latest research by Andrew Rose (2007) on exits from currency unions reveals that 'what shapes currency unions around the world is not what the received theory predicts … the most striking facts are that aggregate macroeconomic features of the economy do a poor job in predicting current union exits …' .7 7Quoted from Rose's own summary in 'Why Have Currency Unions Dissolved? A Test of Optimum Currency Area Theory', VOX, 6 February 2008, http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/902, accessed 15 March 2008. And this gap is why while Gourinchas and Rey (2007) and Curcuru et al. (2008) debate the numbers on whether a differential financial return actually exists for US holders of foreign assets versus foreign holders of US assets, which could rationalize the capital flows temporarily, but cannot explain them. At some point, the very fact that long-term holdings of US dollar assets by foreigners have been a losing proposition in relative as well as absolute terms, has to be taken at face value: these assets were and are held for non-financial reasons, at least in part. The United States' political leadership in security, commercial and even cultural affairs globally has a critical impact on the usage of the dollar in the monetary realm.8 8In an important recent book, Findlay and O'Rourke (2007) make a parallel case (in much greater depth) that war and security relations played a bigger role than technology (i.e. pure economic incentives) in determining the expansion and pattern of global trade over the last several centuries. Other governments' reserve currency holdings and exchange rate management are importantly influenced by security ties, and thus decisions to link to the dollar (and to accumulate dollar reserves for intervention) from Taiwan to Saudi Arabia to Panama depend as much on foreign policy as economics. Private decisions to invest in the United States, both at the corporate level and by individuals, are supported by the desire to gain insider access to key decision-making processes and to membership in transnational elites; in fact, it is this desire for membership and access that is a major source of the financially unrewarding investments made by foreigners in the United States – and thus of the United States' exorbitant privilege to pay for its current account deficits in its own currency. The European Union, let alone the eurozone itself, is unable or unwilling to offer these systemic or security benefits beyond a very limited area, and thus is fundamentally limited in its ability to attract currency adherents, despite the success of the euro on its own terms as a currency and store of value. The most attention-getting aspect of the supposed displacement of the dollar by the euro is the rising share of euros in official reserves held by governments and central banks. It is the most easily quantifiable and trackable aspect of the shift, as analysed by Chinn and Frankel (2007). Often, a statement by a sovereign wealth fund or central bank, particularly if from East Asia, that it is thinking of buying fewer dollar-denominated assets gets wide reportage and some market attention. In broad terms the widely held assumption is that euros and dollars play a zero-sum game in official portfolio holdings – when dollar holdings decline, euro holdings rise, and yen, sterling and other currencies are largely irrelevant.9 9In contrast to Portes et al. (2006), Truman and Dowson (2008) find that the euro has not 'benefited' from reserve diversification; the pound sterling and other currencies have gained disproportionately relative to the low level of their initial shares as developing countries have built up their reserve totals (see 1, 2). Yet, the broad data pattern remains that currency shares in central bank portfolios are very persistent over time.10 10As Eichengreen (2005) points out, the network externality argument in favour of a single currency does not really make sense for official reserve holders (and some private agents) for whom the whole point of reserves is to diversify. This provides additional reason for concern about how to interpret the observed importance of lagged reserve shares in forecasting future reserve shares. See Figure 1 for a long-term view on the exchange rate of the dollar, its reserve share and the US share in global GDP, the latter two of which vary little over the entire post-Bretton Woods period. There is a literature that tries to model the portfolio behaviour of central banks and other official reserve holders, which should clarify how these decisions are made and the reasons for such stability. In fact, it only contributes to the glaring need for non-financial variables to explain official reserve behaviour, because the financial models demonstrate how far the current holdings are from optimal allocations from a risk management perspective. The long view on dollar decline Sources: Data from 1973 to 1994 are taken from Table I.2 in the respective year's IMF Annual Report. Data since 1995 are taken from the IMF COFER database. Trade-weighted USD index are from Federal Reserve Statistical Release. GDP data from 1970–79 are taken from Angus Maddison's World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1-2003 AD (http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/). Data since 1980 are taken from IMF WEO, October 2007. In a sophisticated recent example, Portes et al. (2006), 'develop a dynamic mean-variance optimization framework with portfolio rebalancing costs to estimate optimal portfolio weights among the main international currencies … adding in constraints that reflect a central bank's desire to hold a sizable portion of its portfolio in the currencies of its peg, its foreign debt, and its international trade'. Absent a strong assumption that the dollar is the 'reference (risk-free) currency', which already assumes the persistence result, they cannot generate in their 'optimizer' holdings of the dollar anywhere close to those levels observed11 11An earlier version of their paper (2005) without this assumption finds that 'While on average, among [Brazil, China, India, and Russia], the optimization gives the dollar a weight of 20%–25%, the actual share is forty percentage points higher at 65%', even when taking trade, debt and pegging ties into account. – and in so doing illustrate the 'huge foregone diversification losses' from a solely financial perspective that the dollar's dominance embodies. Similarly, the euro would have an optimum weight (share) lower than that already observed in reserve holdings according to their optimizer. Even with the inclusion of trade/debt/peg additional variables beyond those in Chinn and Frankel (2007), following Eichengreen and Mathieson (2000), Portes et al. (2006) generate predictions that India and China should be increasing their shares of yen reserves (not happening and not going to), and that Brazil and Russia should be significantly increasing their shares of euro reserves (yes to the latter, no to the former) – all of which results seem to emphasize that the choices about pegs, if not economic patterns more broadly, in practice are dominated by security concerns and diplomatic relationships. It is no coincidence that Russia is the only one of these four major emerging markets to actively move into the euro, even when all four face substantial financial expense and risk from not reallocating their portfolios, given their dollar exposure on accumulated reserves. Given this gap between what a financially optimizing portfolio allocation strategy would encourage for reserve allocation and what is observed in reality, it should be no surprise that there is no simple relationship between even sustained movements in exchange rates and reserve shares. As well-explained by Lim (2006), most central banks appear to have fixed target allocations for their portfolios, and pursue a rebalancing strategy to maintain those allocations, buying more of the lesser-valued assets as their exchange rate value declines, and vice versa (see also Truman and Wong 2006). Lim (2006) points out that this rebalancing behaviour can be distinguished from the behaviour of central banks that are seeking to maximize the short-run financial value of their portfolios in terms of how much and in which direction reserves respond to exchange rate movements. Rebalancing central banks will buy more of what declines in value (reserves in a depreciating currency) to return their portfolio allocations to their original proportions, so long as that underlying desired proportion is unchanged. Central banks that seek to maximize short-term returns, or to minimize short-term losses, will tend to change their ideal allocation of their portfolio when they perceive a trend going against one piece of their portfolio. In short, they will sell off the reserves held in depreciating currencies. So it is worthwhile to document that managers of official reserves have continued to largely maintain persistent currency allocations, and that those allocations are far too dollar-heavy to be financially optimal, even with recent developments in the US economy and the euro–dollar exchange rate. As of the latest available data on official reserves (the IMF's COFER data which runs to 2007Q3), it is clear that diversification away from the US dollar has remained gradual over the past few years, consistent with the past behaviour. Among those countries that report the currency composition of their reserves to the IMF, the dollar's share of total reserves has fallen from 72% in 2002Q1, when the trade-weighted dollar was at a peak, to 64% in 2007Q3. This 8% drop in share is to be compared with a depreciation of the dollar against the SDR by 20% and bilaterally against the euro by 39% over the same period. Even the sustained dollar depreciation trend does not appear to have had a commensurate effect on dollar reserves. Truman and Dowson (2008) further make the case that diversification out of dollars has been predominantly what they term 'passive', meaning the result of the declining relative value of already held dollar reserves versus other currencies, rather than due to 'active' diversification away from new dollar purchases or by sales of dollar reserves with intent.12 12I am grateful to Ted Truman for discussion of these issues, and to him and Doug Dowson for sharing their analysis of COFER data (see Truman and Dowson 2008), which this section complements on the euro side. The use and interpretation of that data here, however, is solely my own responsibility. They re-calculate the changes over time in the COFER data in national currency (or quantity) terms in order to distinguish these effects, and find that only $30 billion a year in total of the reserves covered in the data set could be termed actively diversified out of dollar holdings. That is less than 10% of the nearly $400 billion per year in dollar reserves that foreign central banks added during the 1999Q1–2007Q3 period. Following their approach, I compute the changes in shares of the euro in official reserves in the available data, distinguishing between value shares, which vary with the exchange rate movements, and national currency denominated quantity shares. See 2, 3 for the results for developing and domestic economies, respectively. As shown in both figures as a benchmark, the euro has risen against the SDR (and thus a basket of world currencies) steadily since mid-2000, and is up a cumulative 30%. The euro's appreciation against the SDR being greater than the dollar's 20% decline against the SDR, it indicates a broader appreciation of the euro globally. The euro in developing countries reserves, 1999–present Source: IMF rates database; IMF COFER database.Note: End-of-quarter values were used for SDRs per euro. The euro in industrial countries reserves, 1999–present Source: IMF rates database; IMF COFER database.Note: End-of-quarter values were used for SDRs per euro. Since a near-step increase in euro shares of developing country reserves in mid-2002, however, the euro share of reserves has fluctuated in a small range, depicted in Figure 2. The share of reserves has remained between 24% and 28% of total, returning from the peak in 2005Q2 to just over 25% in 2007Q3. Both of these movements in reserve shares at the margin – increasingly into the euro following the dollar peak and out of the euro following the euro run-up – are consistent with a rebalancing approach by central banks, as discussed in Lim (2006) and Truman and Wong (2006). This is of course also the flip side of Truman and Dowson's (2008) finding that most of the shift in the dollar quantity share of developing country reserves since 2004Q2 has been balanced by an increase in sterling and other currencies, and not in the euro. Computed on a value basis, the euro's share of reserves is of course higher, but has stayed between 27% and 30% since 2003Q3, and has also come down in recent quarters. For the industrial countries, the picture shown in Figure 3 is perhaps even more surprising. Despite the steady appreciation of the euro, the euro quantity share of their reserves declines markedly from a high of 22% in 2002Q4 to 17% in 2004Q1. This would seem to be the effect of the massive currency intervention by Japan in the dollar–yen market in 2003 and the first quarter of 2004, when the Japanese government bought up huge amounts of dollars, but not euros (and other Asian central banks pursued similar strategies on much smaller scales), and thus is a one-time shock. But looking at the three-plus years since the Japanese intervention available in the data, the euro share of industrial country reserves has barely moved in quantity terms, staying between 17.0% and 17.6% of the total. While the industrial country totals are dominated by Japan, the United States, the United Kingdom, and the eurozone members themselves, this still implies that none of the major economies actively shifted their reserves into euros over the period at all. The value share of euro reserves has fluctuated much more markedly up and down over the period, between a high of nearly 24% and a low just over 19%, despite the relatively steady appreciation of the euro against the dollar and the SDR. The last four or five quarters do show an upward trend, which of course reflects recent euro–dollar exchange rate developments, and could of course accelerate – but to present still leaves the euro share, even in value terms, in industrial country reserves below 23%. It is worth emphasizing (as Setser 2007; Truman and Dowson 2008, among others, point out) that the main driver in the accumulation of official reserves in this decade is not the relative allocation of euros versus dollars. Instead, the big story is the massive accumulation of dollar reserves by Asian developing countries, and the broader rise of developing country reserves as a share of the global total as their national incomes have risen on the back of export-led growth. This massive accumulation of reserves in East and South Asia is in part brought about by foreign exchange intervention to undervalue their currencies, and in part to ensure that incumbent governments will have sufficient reserves to deter speculative attacks on their currencies of the sort that occurred in 1997–98.13 13Some analysts have pointed out that the amount of reserves accumulated by these countries far exceeds the quantity required for self-insurance against currency crises, which arguably gives credence to the mercantilist motivation for export-led growth, and certainly demonstrates that slow-moving 'network effects' or changes in the size of currency areas cannot account for these decisions (in estimations, the missing mass problem remains). On the latest COFER data, developing country reserves are now 75% of the total in official hands, even counting Japan. It seems that for the developing countries, perhaps in part for reasons of the denomination shares of their trade and external debt (see Portes et al. 2006), their ideal allocation is heavier on euros relative to dollars than in the industrial countries. That heavier allocation into euros for the developing countries, however, on Portes et al.'s (2006) optimal portfolio is still well below 30%, and that is consistent with the range of values seen for the euro share in Figure 1 here. Thus, a relative gain in the share of official reserves held and managed by developing countries versus those in industrial countries should lead to an increase in the overall share of reserves held in euros, but only to the point of the higher euro share that fits their needs. In other words, some of the apparent recent reallocation of dollar to euro reserves reflects the different underlying portfolio preferences of the developing countries, but not an obvious revision upward of the desired steady-state share of euros in either developing or industrial country portfolios. It remains possible that this time is different, that the next COFER data update showing 2007Q4 or 2008Q1 developments will display such a shift, but through the financial turbulence and euro appreciation of 2007Q3 that has not been happening. And if the reserve shares held in the official sector in Asia and beyond do not respond to these exchange rate developments, but continue to show persistence in dollar allocations, then the missing mass issue is only brought into sharper relief. A key determinant of a country's public sector demand for a foreign currency is the existence or not of an exchange rate peg to that foreign currency. The existence or not of an explicit official currency peg, however, understates the influence of these relationships on

Referência(s)
Altmetric
PlumX