Artigo Acesso aberto Revisado por pares

The Economics of Labor Coercion

2011; Wiley; Volume: 79; Issue: 2 Linguagem: Inglês

10.3982/ecta8963

ISSN

1468-0262

Autores

Daron Acemoğlu, Alexander Wolitzky,

Tópico(s)

Economic Policies and Impacts

Resumo

EconometricaVolume 79, Issue 2 p. 555-600 The Economics of Labor Coercion Daron Acemoglu, Daron Acemoglu Dept. of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, E52-371, Cambridge, MA 02142-1347, U.S.A. and Canadian Institute for Advanced Research; [email protected]Search for more papers by this authorAlexander Wolitzky, Alexander Wolitzky Dept. of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, MA 02142-1347, U.S.A.; [email protected] We thank Stephen Morris, Andrew Postlewaite, four anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research, the Determinants of Social Conflict Conference, and MIT for useful comments and suggestions.Search for more papers by this author Daron Acemoglu, Daron Acemoglu Dept. of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, E52-371, Cambridge, MA 02142-1347, U.S.A. and Canadian Institute for Advanced Research; [email protected]Search for more papers by this authorAlexander Wolitzky, Alexander Wolitzky Dept. of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, MA 02142-1347, U.S.A.; [email protected] We thank Stephen Morris, Andrew Postlewaite, four anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research, the Determinants of Social Conflict Conference, and MIT for useful comments and suggestions.Search for more papers by this author First published: 14 February 2011 https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA8963Citations: 114 AboutPDF ToolsRequest permissionExport citationAdd to favoritesTrack citation ShareShare Give accessShare full text accessShare full-text accessPlease review our Terms and Conditions of Use and check box below to share full-text version of article.I have read and accept the Wiley Online Library Terms and Conditions of UseShareable LinkUse the link below to share a full-text version of this article with your friends and colleagues. Learn more.Copy URL Share a linkShare onEmailFacebookTwitterLinkedInRedditWechat Abstract The majority of labor transactions throughout much of history and a significant fraction of such transactions in many developing countries today are “coercive,” in the sense that force or the threat of force plays a central role in convincing workers to accept employment or its terms. We propose a tractable principal–agent model of coercion, based on the idea that coercive activities by employers, or “guns,” affect the participation constraint of workers. We show that coercion and effort are complements, so that coercion increases effort, but coercion always reduces utilitarian social welfare. Better outside options for workers reduce coercion because of the complementarity between coercion and effort: workers with a better outside option exert lower effort in equilibrium and thus are coerced less. Greater demand for labor increases coercion because it increases equilibrium effort. We investigate the interaction between outside options, market prices, and other economic variables by embedding the (coercive) principal–agent relationship in a general equilibrium setup, and studying when and how labor scarcity encourages coercion. General (market) equilibrium interactions working through the price of output lead to a positive relationship between labor scarcity and coercion along the lines of ideas suggested by Domar, while interactions those working through the outside option lead to a negative relationship similar to ideas advanced in neo-Malthusian historical analyses of the decline of feudalism. In net, a decline in available labor increases coercion in general equilibrium if and only if its direct (partial equilibrium) effect is to increase the price of output by more than it increases outside options. Our model also suggests that markets in slaves make slaves worse off, conditional on enslavement, and that coercion is more viable in industries that do not require relationship-specific investment by workers. References Acemoglu, D., and J. S. Pischke (1999): “The Structure of Wages and Investment in General Training,” Journal of Political Economy, 107, 539–572. DOI: 10.1086/250071 Acemoglu, D., and A. Wolitzky (2011): “ Supplement to ‘The Economics of Labor Coercion’,” Econometrica Supplemental Material, 79, http://www.econometricsociety.org/ecta/Supmat/8963_extensions.pdf. Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson (2002): “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1231–1294. DOI: 10.1162/003355302320935025 B. Andrees, and P. Belser (Eds.) (2009): Forced Labor: Coercion and Exploitation in the Private Economy. Boulder : Lynne Rienner Publishers. Aston, T. H., and C. H. E. Philpin (1987): The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press. Barzel, Y. (1977): “An Economic Analysis of Slavery,” Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 87–110. DOI: 10.1086/466893 Basu, K. (1986): “One Kind of Power,” Oxford Economic Papers, 38, 259–282. Bergstrom, T. (1971): “On the Existence and Optimality of Competitive Equilibrium for a Slave Economy,” Review of Economic Studies, 38, 23–36. DOI: 10.2307/2296619 Bloom, J. (1998): The End of the Old Order in Rural Europe. Princeton : Princeton University Press. Brenner, R. (1976): “Agrarian Class-Structure and Economic-Development in Pre-Industrial Europe,” Past and Present, 70, 30–75. DOI: 10.1093/past/70.1.30 Canarella, G., and J. Tomaske (1975): “The Optimal Utilization of Slaves,” Journal of Economic History, 36, 621–629. DOI: 10.1017/S0022050700075665 Chwe, M. (1990): “Why Were Workers Whipped? Pain in a Principal–Agent Model Economic Journal, 100, 1109–1121. DOI: 10.2307/2233961 Conning, J. (2004): “ On the Causes of Slavery or Serfdom and the Roads to Agrarian Capitalism: Domar's Hypothesis Revisited,” Manuscript, Hunter College . Conrad, A. H., and J. R. Meyer (1958): “The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South,” Journal of Political Economy, 66, 95–122. DOI: 10.1086/258020 Curtin, P. D. (1990): The Rise and Fall of the Plantation Complex. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press. Davis, D. B. (2006): Inhuman Bondage: The Rise and Fall of Slavery in the New World. Oxford : Oxford University Press. Domar, E. D. (1970): “The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis,” Journal of Economic History, 30, 18–32. Dow, G. K. (1993): “Why Capital Hires Labor: A Bargaining Perspective,” American Economic Review, 83, 118–134. Fenoaltea, S. (1984): “Slavery in Comparative Perspective: A Model,” Journal of Economic History, 44, 635–638. DOI: 10.1017/S0022050700032307 Findlay, R. (1975): “Slavery, Incentives, and Manumission: A Theoretical Model,” Journal of Economic History, 44, 923–933. Finley, M. I. (1976): “A Peculiar Institution? Times Literary Supplement, 3877, 819–821. Fogel, R. W., and S. L. Engerman (1974): Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, 2 Volumes. Boston : Little Brown. Genicot, G. (2002): “Bonded Labor and Serfdom: A Paradox of Voluntary Choice,” Journal of Development Economics, 67, 101–127. DOI: 10.1016/S0304-3878(01)00179-1 Grossman, S. J., and O. D. Hart (1986): “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691–719. DOI: 10.1086/261404 Habakkuk, H. J. (1958): “The Economic History of Modern Britain,” Journal of Economic History, 18, 486–501. International Labor Organization (2009): Report of the Director-General: The Cost of Coercion. Geneve , Switzerland : International Labour Office. Key, V. O., Jr. (1949): Southern Politics: In State and Nation. New York : Vintage Books. Klein, H. S., and B. Vinson (2007): African Slavery in Latin America and the Caribbean. New York : Oxford University Press. Lagerlöf, N. (2009): “Slavery and Other Property Rights,” Review of Economic Studies, 76, 319–342. DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00511.x Le Roy Ladurie, E. (1977): The Peasants of Languedoc. Urbana , IL : University of Illinois Press. Translated by John Day. Lockhart, J. (2000): Of Things of the Indies: Essays Old and New in Early in American History. Stanford : Stanford University Press. Lockhart, J., and S. B. Schwartz (1983): Early Latin America: A History of Colonial Spanish Latin America and Brazil. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press. Lovejoy, P. E. (2000): Transformations of Slavery: A History of Slavery in Africa ( Second Ed.). Cambridge : University of Cambridge Press. Mas-Collel, A. (1984): “On a Theorem of Schmeidler,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 13, 201–206. DOI: 10.1016/0304-4068(84)90029-6 Meltzer, M. (1993): Slavery: A World History. New York : DeCapo Press. Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts (1994): “Comparing Equilibria,” American Economic Review, 84, 441–459. Naidu, S., and N. Yuchtman (2009): “ How Green Was My Valley? Coercive Contract Enforcement in 19th Century Industrial Britain,” Mimeo, Harvard University . Naqvi, N., and F. Wemhöner (1995): “Power, Coercion, and the Games Landlords Play,” Journal of Development Economics, 47, 191–205. DOI: 10.1016/0304-3878(95)00010-N North, D. C., and R. T. Thomas (1971): “The Rise and Fall of the Manorial System: A Theoretical Model,” Journal of Economic History, 31, 777–803. DOI: 10.1017/S0022050700074623 Patterson, O. (1982): Slavery and Social Death: A Comparative Study. Cambridge : Harvard University Press. Postan, M. M. (1973): Cambridge Economic History of Europe: Expanding Europe in the 16th and 17th Centuries. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press. Ransom, R. L., and R. Sutch (1975): “The Impact of the Civil War and of Emancipation on Southern Agriculture,” Explorations in Economic History, 12, 1–28. DOI: 10.1016/0014-4983(75)90051-0 Ransom, R. L., and R. Sutch (1977): One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press. Sherstyuk, K. (2000): “Performance Standards and Incentive Pay in Agency Contracts,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102, 725–736. DOI: 10.1111/1467-9442.00223 Topkis, D. M. (1998): Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton , NJ : Princeton University Press. Wright, G. (1978): The Political Economy of the Cotton South: Households, Markets, and Wealth in the Nineteenth Century. New York : Norton. Citing Literature Volume79, Issue2March 2011Pages 555-600 ReferencesRelatedInformation

Referência(s)